This is a bit less tongue in cheek, or even opinionated,
than some of my other posts. The Banking Crisis was without a doubt one of the
defining events of the first decade of the 21st century. Its shadow
still falls across discussions on politics, regulation, the role of the state,
and economic theory. But despite that little evidence is publicly presented as
to the causes of the crisis, or the long run costs it has incurred. This is therefore an attempt to put some
numbers on the costs to the taxpayers of ‘bailing out the banks’.
..
A Note on Figures; The majority of this post is sourced from
reports completed by the National Audit Office and the Treasury Select Committee,
however, as a result of the this some of the figures are based around 2009-10
rather than 2010-11 or more recent.
Indirect and Cash
Stability was returned to the UK banking sector through two
main mechanisms – direct (or cash) and indirect. Cash injections were used to
buy shares and provide loans to (amongst others) Lloyds TSB, RBS, Northern Rock
and Bradford & Bingley. These ‘direct’ interventions cost real money in the
here-and-now, and, assuming no more major impacts to the system, it is
predominately these costs which will need to recovered or written off by H.M.
Government.
Indirect costs took the form of guarantees and indemnities provided
through three special purpose vehicles (The Asset Protection Scheme, Credit
Guarantee Scheme and Special Liquidity Scheme). Although significantly larger
than the cash costs to the Treasury, these ‘indirect’ costs are only
crystallised in the event of further default or difficulty in the Banking
sector. Peaking at a potential exposure of
nearly £1 trillion (Maintaining the financial stability of UK banks; update on
the support schemes. National Audit Office, Dec 2010, reference 676, Key findings)
the possible costs of these guarantees have fallen to an estimated £512 as at
the end of 2010.
I’m largely going to ignore indirect costs from now on. Reports from the Treasury and NAO seem to
suggest these guarantees are not going to be required, and many of the schemes
are looking to wind down by 2014 (et al). This reflects a wider truth that the
banking sector suffered from a lack of liquidity and confidence, rather than
necessarily a paper bankruptcy (this is especially true for Northern Rock which
was in a stable position on paper, but a loss of confidence caused it to fail
due to a cash flow problem). The government stepping in with the ‘big guns’ of
unlimited asset guarantees restored confidence, reduced the need for immediate
liquidity, and ended the problem.
Cash Costs
The total cash cost of the bank bailout was around £133
billion (et al, Summary (2)) this covered the purchase of shares in RBS and
Lloyds, and cash loaned to banks wholly owned by the government at this point
(predominately Northern Rock and Bradford & Bingley). It also covers loans
to various compensation schemes to cover client withdrawals.
These funds were not
taken from other governmental budgets, but rather borrowed in their entirety.
The National Audit Office puts the cost of servicing this debt at approximately
£5 billion / year (or an annual interest rate of 3.76%). This on-going cost
will exist as long as the loans and shareholdings remain outstanding.
From a practical perspective the bank bailout has therefore
incurred a cash-flow cost of £5 billion per year, with the caveat that a future
loss may be crystallised when the various share holdings are sold. This £5
billion forms approximately 11% of an annual interest bill of £46 billion (2012
Budget Executive Summary) or 0.7% of total government spending.
The likely losses incurred by a sell-off of the shares in
RBS and Lloyds will depend entirely on the prevailing share price, and any
pricing arrangements put in place to secure a buyer. So, where does that leave us at present?
RBS
The calculation of the current value of the government’s
holding in RBS is slightly complicated by the introduction of “B” shares in
2009. In addition to its holding of 65% of the ordinary shares in RBS, the
Government also owns 39 billion “B” shares, created to allow a further injection
of cash into the Bank without further ordinary share purchases. These B shares
are valued at 50p each, receive a 250% preference dividend, and do not allow
voting rights.
These “B” shares were issued at a value of 50p, which conveniently
ties in with an approximate ‘buy in’ price for the government’s ordinary RBS
shares of around 50p as well. All this means that while a line by line analysis
of the government’s holdings is out of the scope of this post, we can get a
reasonable estimate of the current position by comparing the current ordinary
share price to 50p. Anything above would equate to gains come a sale, anything
below a loss.
(Note; RBS had a 10:1 corporate action after the bailout,
this means the ‘buy in’ prices for the government need to be multiplied by 10
if you want to compare to current prices).
At the current market price of £3.39, the government is facing
a loss of 32%, or £17bn.
Lloyds
Luckily the Lloyds figures don’t seem quite so convoluted.
The government bought a 41% stake in Lloyds for £21billion. This was entirely
in ordinary shares, and therefore the published market capitalisation figure
can be used to determine the value of a 41% stake. Using this approach a
current value of £15.2billion, or a paper loss of just under £7bn is reached.
Options
The government seems to have several avenues on how to
proceed with regards to its shareholdings. Although I’m going to provide some
commentary on these, I’d highlight these are my own opinions, not quotes or
paraphrasing from official sources.
1. SELL IT ALL!!
There is always the option for the government to just drop their holdings and get out now. What this would actually do to the share price is troublesome, since it would almost inevitably precipitate a complete collapse in the already struggling shares, even assuming a buyer could be found. In practice this probably isn’t a realistic option.
There is always the option for the government to just drop their holdings and get out now. What this would actually do to the share price is troublesome, since it would almost inevitably precipitate a complete collapse in the already struggling shares, even assuming a buyer could be found. In practice this probably isn’t a realistic option.
2. Bit now, bit later
I’m putting this in for the sake of completeness, though it
smacks more of a political move than an economic one. Selling off some of the holdings in the two banks
would reduce the spectre of ‘state ownership’ and raise a bit of cash, but it
would also lock in losses with comparably few tangible benefits.
3. Public-ize RBS
A rather radical move that was floated at one point was to
just give the government’s shares to the taxpaying public. Probably a nice
voter winner, but I have to agree with Vince Cable’s recent comments that this
was unlikely to happen. Not only would this crystallise the full value of the
bail out as a loss to the government, it would potentially hammer the share
price when the markets become flooded with shares being sold by private
investors.
4. Do nothing
Unless a single, large, buyer (such as a sovereign wealth
fund) can be found, this is probably what’s going to happen. There is always
the long run chance that the share price will recover, and once Lloyds and RBS
find their feet they will begin paying dividends, which will largely go straight
into the Treasury. This is also what I’d
personally advocate. Although both Lloyds and RBS have currently suspended paying
a dividend while they repair their balance sheets and pay down liabilities, in
the long run (it is an oft-quoted truth that shares should be held for at least
5-10 years), a return to dividend payments of around 4.6% (HSBC’s average
yield), would both cover the costs of servicing the underlying debts incurred
in purchasing the shares, and even offer a gradual net profit on the deal.
To Re-Cap
Just to bring all of these points together, and to provide a
quick summary for use against the ranks of “Argh the government is collapsing
because of the costs of propping up the banks,”
·
The Government provide around £133bn in cash to
the banking sector.
·
That £133 billion was borrowed at an effective
rate of around 3.75% per annum, incurring a servicing charge of £5 billion per
annum.
·
For that investment the government got a stake
in RBS and Lloyds which is currently worth around £24billion less than was paid
for it.
·
That loss isn’t going to be crystallised any
time soon since it looks improbable that a major sale of RBS or Lloyds will take
place. As such the £24 billion is only a ‘paper’ loss.
If Today Were Year
ZERO
Much is made, both in the media, and by people in general,
about how the current social/economic predicament is caused by having to bail
out the banks. What I hope the above has shown is that the actual, real, cash
cost, of the banking crisis is currently around £5 billion a year. A fairly
irrelevant figure compared to the £638 billion a year annual budget.
Another way of looking at this is that if all historic data,
opinions and knowledge were wiped today, and then the government’s figures
re-calculated based on outgoings and incomings today, the costs of the financial sector bailout would account for
11% of the national debt. While I would not try and claim 11% is immaterial, it
means that 89% of the nation’s accumulated debt has to do with decisions
unrelated to the bank bailout.
Seven Fat Cows, Seven
Thin Cows
The concept of saving when things are good, to cover you
when things go wrong has been around so long its spawned innumerable clichés.
Never-the-less it’s a view which is largely ignored with regards to the financial
sector. I’m going to wrap this analysis up by providing some figures to show
that the financial sector provided far more in tax receipts than it eventually
claimed in bail outs.
Unfortunately the readily available information available on
the taxes paid by the financial sector only goes back to 2005/6. However, using
this as a starting year, the tax receipts from PAYE and Corporation Tax
(including the banking levy), as provided by HMRC (Pay-As-You-Earn and corporate
tax receipts from the banking sector, august 2012, table 1), stand at £147
billion.
This figure alone covers the £133 billion cash bail out
required, and that’s excluding the ‘boom years’ from the beginning of the 2000s
through to 2005. While I don’t expect any government to simply sequester away
huge parts of its tax take for the express purpose of then bailing out the
economy when things turn sour, I do expect an acknowledgement that the
government earned vast receipts from the financial industry throughout the boom
years, and is still in a net position with regards to the banks.
Conclusion
In conclusion I’m going to reiterate a point that has run
throughout this post. Financial costs can always be broken down into direct and
indirect costs. However, much of commentary on the banking sector compares the theoretical
‘worst case’ scenario where all of
the indirect costs materialise, with the immediate direct benefits (the £20
billion a year in tax the sector currently pays). Not only is this grossly
unfair, it’s also completely misleading. Considering only the direct cash costs
to the economy the bank bailout cost £5 billion a year. This is a trivial cost
compared to the £120 billion a year spending deficit the current and previous
government’s social and welfare policies have necessitated. Should the further
£500 billion of contingent indirect costs be incurred we are envisaging a
society where two huge corporations have been wiped out of existence taking all of their assets and holdings with
them, where tens of thousands of business have gone bankrupt overnight, again
without leaving behind any assets, and where entire cities worth of housing has
vanished into holes in the ground. If we ever end up in that situation the
problems of macro-economic government spending are going to be very, very, far
down our list of priorities.
/Z
No comments:
Post a Comment